In response to popular demand (i.e., a recent conversation), I've decided that it's time for more cat pix. So here goes, with quiz question:
I wonder if one can tell just from these two pictures who is the calmer, and who the crazier, of these two brothers (whom I would presume are genetically just half-siblings). Whether or not the pictures give it away, it's not a close call.
Here's Gary:
And here's Sylvester:
So, whaddaya think?
Unfair but balanced commentary on tax and budget policy, contemporary U.S. politics and culture, and whatever else happens to come up
Thursday, January 31, 2019
Wednesday, January 30, 2019
NYU Tax Policy Colloquium, week 2: Rebecca Kysar's Unraveling the Tax Treaty
Yesterday at the
Tax Policy Colloquium, Rebecca Kysar of Fordham Law School presented Unravelingthe Tax Treaty. Here are some of my thoughts regarding this very interesting
paper and the issues it raises.
Bilateral tax
treaties are the subject of a flourishing sub-literature that has often, and
perhaps increasingly, criticized their impact on developing countries in
particular. The paper explores extending
this critique to the United States, e.g., because, as a net capital importer
these days, we may tend to lose current tax revenue from treaties’ standard
practice of having the two treaty partners mutually surrender source taxing
jurisdiction with respect to the other’s residents.
For purposes of
thinking about the issues that the paper raises, I find the following outline
of main treaty provisions helpful. Bilateral tax treaties frequently include
the main six types of provisions, among others:
1) Residency/LOB rules – Treaty
benefits are accorded to residents of the two treaty partners. However,
reflecting corporate residence’s inherently limited meaningfulness as a
concept, there may be “limitation on benefit” (LOB) rules that aim to defeat
“treaty-shopping” by denying treaty benefits to, say, entities that are
residents of one of the jurisdictions but that are functioning as mere
conduits.
2) Permanent establishment (PE) rules
– Treaty partners generally agree not to tax each others’ residents’ business
profits on a source basis in the absence of a “permanent establishment” (PE) in
the source jurisdiction – e.g., an office with dependent agents working there.
3) Withholding taxes – Countries
frequently tax domestic source dividend, interest, and/or royalty income that
is paid to nonresidents. Given the collection and enforcement problems that
might otherwise arise, this is done via withholding taxes that have a fixed
rate and are gross basis (i.e., no deductions are allowed). For example, the U.S. by statute has a 30%
withholding tax. In treaties, however,
countries may reciprocally agree to a charge a lower withholding tax rate
(e.g., 15%, 5%, or even 0%) to each other’s residents.
4) Anti-“double taxation” rules
– I’m putting “double taxation” in scare quotes here for a reason. As I discuss
below, the concept at issue here is perhaps better described other than as one of double
taxation. But there can be good reason
for one not to like the result whereby cross-border investment is
tax-discouraged, such as by reason of its being fully taxed in both the
residence jurisdiction from whence it came, and the source jurisdiction to
which it went. Treaties may address this problem by requiring that each treaty
partner, with respect to its residents, either exempt foreign source income
(FSI) earned in the other jurisdiction, or grant foreign tax credits with
respect to the taxes imposed by the source country. The tax treaties also
typically provide mechanisms for achieving consistent treatment if otherwise
each country would treat the same income as earned within its own borders.
5) Nondiscrimination
– Treaty partners may agree not to have tax rules discriminating against each
others’ residents for tax purposes (although the provisions tend to be quite
narrowly drawn).
6) Information exchange, etc. –
Treaties also contain lots more types of provisions, which I will here
cavalierly funnel into a catch-all, albeit noting in particular information
exchange between the two sovereigns as it’s an important aspect that treaty
critics often praise.
A number of
further common treaty provisions might merit separate coverage due to their
potential importance. For example, treaties may indicate that one should apply
an arm’s length standard to transactions between commonly owned affiliates, supporting
the use of transfer pricing. But these provisions are not as extensively
discussed in the Kysar paper as those listed above.
The paper’s main
arguments are to the effect that (a) 2 and 3 are bad, (b) 4 and 5 are poorly
defined and/or not needed, and (6) can be done separately. For reasons of time and space, I’ll just discuss (a) here.
WHY CEDE SOURCE-BASED TAX JURISDICTION RE.
NON-PE BUSINESS INCOME AND PASSIVE INCOME?
Features 2 and 3
above cede source-based tax jurisdiction with respect to non-PE business income
and passive income. This leads to the question: Why would one ever reduce
optionality / future flexibility by ceding something in advance? There are 3
main answers that one could offer in this context, pertaining in turn to
pre-commitment, reciprocity, and coordination.
Pre-commitment – Retaining
discretion for future policy choices is a bad thing if one is sufficiently
likely to misuse it. (This of course is the “tie Odysseus to the mast” line of
argument.) Governments may benefit, for example, from committing in advance
against ex post expropriation of inbound investment. In the realm of free
trade, if we posit that tariffs are generally a bad idea, but are too often
produced by protectionist forces even when one doesn’t have a malignant clown
at the helm, free trade treaties serve to pre-commit countries to do what they
would benefit from doing anyway.
The best argument
for applying that line of reasoning here is that small open economies may fail
to benefit from taxing inbound capital. Absent market power, local rents, etc.,
the tax is likely to be borne by locals even if it is nominally paid by the foreigners,
and may impose greater deadweight loss than the alternative tax instruments
that might have been used instead. But the optics of literal tax payment by the
outsiders may be unduly enticing.
This line of
argument seems more likely to apply to withholding taxes on passive income,
than to non-PE business income. For example, foreign multinationals with
valuable IP or trade names may be in a position to earn local rents, so one
might want to tax them without regard to whether they have been able to avoid
crossing the PE threshold.
Reciprocity – A tax treaty’s two
parties reciprocally recede. So one’s loss of source-based taxing jurisdiction
is offset by the other side’s so receding with respect to one’s own residents.
In a pure
symmetry case where investment flows, income earned, tax rates, etc., are
completely the same, the revenues foregone equal those that the other side
foregoes with respect to one’s own residents. The paper notes that, if net
capital importers tend to lose in revenue terms (at least on a current basis)
from the asymmetry between the value at stake on the two sides to the deal,
that is an issue not just for developing countries, but also for developed net
capital importers like the U.S. Agreed that this is relevant to the analysis.
Coordination – If countries
attach positive value to coordinating their tax systems with each others’, and
thereby avoiding peculiar interactions or combined effects, then tax treaties
may offer a valuable coordination device. There has increasingly been concern
that countries’ go-it-alone responses to profit-shifting concerns (e.g.,
digital services tax, UK diverted profits tax, the BEAT, etc.) may interact
with each other in undesired ways. But admittedly existing tax treaties may not
help all that much in coordinating responses.
How much difference does it make?
– To the extent that the U.S. is losing tax base by reason of treaty
concessions with respect to non-PE businesses and withholding taxation, it’s
worth noting that the treaties’ marginal effect is seemingly reduced by
relevant aspects of domestic U.S. tax law. For example, we don’t tax inbound
business income on a source basis unless there is a “U.S. trade or business.”
The legal concept here overlaps considerably with that of finding a “permanent:
establishment.” Likewise, even if we presume that 30% is the truly “intended”
withholding tax rate (rather than serving in part merely to give us something
to negotiate away on behalf of U.S. taxpayers), the extent to which it can be
avoided by, say, using derivative financial instruments (such as notional
principal contracts) instead of directly realizing income that is subject to
withholding tax – and the extent to which (despite recent regulatory
tightening) this might be intended and reasonably so given the “small open
economy” issue – is worth keeping in mind.
Wednesday, January 23, 2019
NYU Tax Policy Colloquium, week 1: Stefanie Stancheva's Taxation and Innovation in the 20th Century
Yesterday we
kicked off the 24th NYU Tax Policy Colloquium, with Stefanie
Stantcheva of the Harvard Economics Department presenting Taxation and Innovation in the 20th Century. Here are some of the main points
that occurred to me about the paper. (I don’t comment here about the
discussions, in order to preserve their off-the-record status – not that this often
matters, but so that no one in attendance will ever need to worry about this question.)
1) Strong empirical results – This
paper is a major success (for Stantcheva and her co-authors: Ufuk Agcigit, John
Grigsby, and Tom Nicholas) because it generates strong and robust empirical
findings, using new datasets that permit them to examine how state and local
personal and corporate income taxes since 1920 may have affected innovation, as
defined by patent quantity and “quality” (measured by citations). They find very significant tax elasticities for
innovation quantity and quality, as thus measured, that are robust across a
range of different specifications. And
while a lot of what they find appears to be “business-stealing” – i.e., mere
shifting of activity from one tax jurisdiction to another – they conclude that
this is not the entire story; there appear also to be (lesser) effects on
overall activity levels.
While the paper
is science not advocacy, it strikes me as potentially important for a broader
set of tax policy debates. A whole lot more would be needed to support some of
the implications that I discuss below, and the authors make no claim that such
support is likely to be found, but it’s nonetheless worth spelling out here why
I think this line of research is of broader interest.
Other empirical
results in the paper that are of interest include (a) its comparison of the
effects of corporate versus personal income tax rates, and (b) its finding that
agglomeration effects, such as the concentration of IP researchers in Silicon Valley,
reduce the tax elasticity of the measured behaviors.
2) Contra Diamond and Saez, Ocasio-Cortez,
et al? – Our era of rising high-end inequality has helped to shift the
Overton window for academic debate, and perhaps even public political debate,
regarding how high marginal rates at the top should be.
Optimal income
taxation (OIT), a literature to which Stantcheva has (elsewhere) made
significant contributions, was long thought to suggest having relatively
flattish rates, for what is essentially a technical or logical reason. OIT aims to maximize a measure of social
welfare, typically based on utilitarian or other summations of individuals’
welfare, by trading off redistributive benefits (from declining marginal
utility or a pro-egalitarian aggregation rule) against efficiency costs. However,
the fact that rate brackets at the very top of the income distribution are
inframarginal (because one is guaranteed to be above them) for so small a
proportion of the people subject to them, as compared to rate brackets lower
down the distribution, pushes against steep rate graduation. E.g., if I know
that I will be earning $1 million or more, and the choices that I am
considering relate only to the question of how much more, then rate brackets
for the first $1 million of my income have no distortionary effects (i.e., only
income effects) on what I decide to do.
An influential paper
from several years back, by Peter Diamond and Emmanuel Saez, nonetheless used
an OIT methodology to support top marginal rates as high as 70%. Their
conclusion relied heavily on (1) empirical evidence of low short-term labor
supply elasticity, which suggested that the deadweight loss from so high a rate
at the top might not be so great, and (2) a view that any lost utility to
people at the very top from the high rates would be subjectively, and/or as a
matter of social welfare function weighting, indistinguishable from zero. Under
the Diamond-Saez paper’s model, one therefore might choose the revenue-maximizing
rate for people at the top of the income distribution. One still, however,
wouldn’t want a more than revenue-maximizing rate.
An admitted
problem with this conclusion was our lack of good knowledge about long-term
labor supply elasticities. However, one may derive additional support for very
high rates, and indeed for more than revenue-maximizing rates at the top, if
one believes (as I do) that extreme high-end wealth concentration can have
negative externalities, e.g., by reason of its (in the words of an NYT op-ed today by Saez and Gabriel Zucman) undermining "democracy against oligarchy” and
creating “corro[sion of] the social contract.”
Under that view, extremely high wealth and income concentration at the
top can be like pollution, which a Pigovian tax would price at marginal cost
rather than aiming at revenue maximization.
As Paul Krugman and
Matthew Yglesias, among others, have noted, this academic research underlies
Alexandra Ocasio-Cortez’s recent call for a 70 percent top marginal rate, which
I view as desirably expanding the Overton window for public policy debate, although
I wouldn’t go all the way there myself for reasons that it would be too
digressive to address here.
So, how is the
Stantcheva paper on innovation’s tax sensitivity relevant to all this? The answer
is that it could point the way towards a new line of argument against very high
marginal rates, in particular at the top where one might expect successful IP
entrepreneurs to find themselves. The point
here is not just that innovation, as measured by the paper, appears to be
highly tax-responsive, but also that there are arguments for its having great
social value.
3) Is “innovation” special? – In my
days (back in the mid-1980s) as a Legislation Attorney at the Joint Committee
on Taxation, I had a colleague whose area of responsibility included the
R&D credit. He personally hated the credit (not that he could do anything
about this preference), despite the fact that our economists loved it, at least
in principle, because they viewed R&D activity as having positive
externalities. He liked to say, in support of his view, that too much of the
activity that would end up qualifying for the credit was of the character of,
say, McDonald’s or Burger King working on their sesame seed buns.
But even leaving aside
knowledge spillovers from businesses’ research that may be more consequential than
improving the sesame seed bun, we know there is some patentable innovation that
appears to have strong positive externalities. Consider iPhones, or else advances
in medical treatment that prolong people’s lives and wellbeing. There is “innovation”
out there that (a) creates new consumer surplus, in that the subjective value
to people of a newly available item exceeds its market price, and/or (b)
increases workers’ productivity, thereby permitting to reach higher levels of
market consumption plus leisure than were previously available to them.
Insofar as high
taxes reduce the amount of such socially valuable innovation, we have positive
externalities from low rates to think about, not just the negative
externalities that Saez and Zucman invoke. Thus, a finding that socially
valuable innovation is reduced – not just shifted around between jurisdictions –
by higher tax rates would complicate the OIT analysis and push back against the
Diamond-Saez-Zucman / Ocasio-Cortez approach.
This is very far
from being established by the Stantcheva paper (as Stantcheva herself would be
the first to agree). But it helps to show why further research, along the lines
that this paper significantly (albeit still preliminarily) advances, is of very
broad interest.
One should also
note the possibility of negative externalities that might be associated with
innovation – e.g., if it increases high-end inequality, creates welfare losses
from Schumpeterian “creative destruction,” and/or involves strategic and defensive
patenting, patent trolling, etc. But in any event the paper helps to point out
the need to think more about possible spillovers from “innovation,” as well as
about long-term labor supply elasticities, when debating top marginal rates.
4) The paper’s quantity and quality
measures of innovation – In keeping with much other IP literature, the
paper uses patents as a measure of innovation quantity, and patent citations as
a measure of innovation quality. This is inevitably open to challenge and
imperfect, as a rich vein of IP literature has been exploring.
5) Policy implications if high tax rates
reduce socially valuable innovation – Even if the paper’s possible and
still speculative broader policy implications are confirmed, there is a whole
lot of instrument choice to think about. E.g., lower rates vs. exempting the
normal return to innovation vs. targeted subsidies for innovation vs. stronger
IP protections. Each tool might have its own set of tradeoffs.
6) Fiscal federalism issues – Some of
the positive spillovers that innovation might yield may operate at the global
level. E.g., insofar as iPhones improve people’s lives, such improvement is not
conditioned on the iPhone’s having been invented within one’s own taxing jurisdiction.
So just as any one country, if it is acting purely selfishly and unilaterally,
lacks the incentive to impose carbon taxes that are priced at global marginal
cost, so it might be expected to disregard or at least undervalue innovation’s
positive spillover effects on outsiders.
On the other
hand, “business-stealing” may be locally beneficial even if not globally so.
Thus, local incentives to encourage innovation might end up being either too
high or too low in the aggregate, but seem likely to be misdirected from a
global social welfare standpoint.
I’ve commented
here mainly on some of the broader implications, albeit as still unknown, that
cause “Taxation and Innovation in the 20th Century” to be of
especial broader interest. But I should also note one more time its yielding
strong and robust empirical findings, of a sort that researchers more commonly wish
for than achieve.
Thursday, January 10, 2019
2019 NYU Tax Policy Colloquium
As it's now less than two weeks to showtime, here is an update on our speaker schedule for the 2019 NYU Tax Policy Colloquium, now including most paper titles:
SCHEDULE FOR 2019 NYU TAX POLICY
COLLOQUIUM
SCHEDULE FOR 2019 NYU TAX POLICY
COLLOQUIUM
(All
sessions meet from 4:00-5:50 pm in Vanderbilt 208, NYU Law School)
1.
Tuesday, January 22 – Stefanie
Stantcheva, Harvard Economics Department. “Taxation and Innovation in the 20th
Century.”
2.
Tuesday, January 29 – Rebecca
Kysar, Fordham Law School. “Unraveling the Tax Treaty.”
3.
Tuesday, February 5 – David
Kamin, NYU Law School. TBD.
4. Tuesday,
February 12
– John Roemer, Yale University Economics and Political Science Departments. “A
Theory of Cooperation in Games With an Application to Market Socialism.”
5.
Tuesday, February 19 – Susan
Morse, University of Texas at Austin Law School. “Government-to-Robot
Enforcement.”
6.
Tuesday, February 26 – Li
Liu, International Monetary Fund. “At a
Cost: The Real Effects of Transfer Pricing Regulations.”
7.
Tuesday, March 5 – Richard
Reinhold, Willkie, Farr, and Gallagher LLP.
[The parsonage allowance and the establishment clause.]
8.
Tuesday, March 12 – Tatiana
Homonoff, NYU Wagner School. “Encouraging
Free Tax Preparation Among Paper Filers: Evidence from a Field Experiment.”
9. Tuesday,
March 26
– Michelle Hanlon, MIT Sloan School of Management. TBD.
10. Tuesday,
April 2
– Omri Marian, University of California at Irvine School of Law. “The Making of International Tax
Law: Empirical Evidence from Natural Language Processing.”
11. Tuesday,
April 9
– Steven Bank, UCLA Law School. “Manufacturing Tax Populism.”
12. Tuesday,
April 16
– Dayanand Manoli, University of Texas at Austin Department of Economics. “Tax Enforcement and Tax Policy:
Evidence on Taxpayer Responses to EITC Correspondence Audits.”
13. Tuesday,
April 23
– Sara Sternberg Greene, Duke Law School.
“A Theory of Poverty: Legal
Immobility.”
14. Tuesday,
April 30
– Wei Cui, University of British Columbia Law School. “The Digital Services
Tax: A Conceptual Defense.”
Wednesday, January 09, 2019
AALS Tax Section panel
This past Saturday (January 5), at the American Association of Law School's Annual Meeting (in New Orleans), I was among the four panelists at an AALS Tax Section panel. The panel was organized and moderated by Shu-Yi Oei, the other panelists were Karen Burke, Ajay Mehrotra, and Leigh Osofsky, and the topic was "The 2017 Tax Changes: One Year Later." For more general background information about the panel, see here (from the Tax Prof blog).
We divided up in advance the particular topics to be discussed by each of us, and here is a very rough effort to reproduce in miniature my comments:
1) What have we learned in the past year about the economic impact of the 2017 tax act?
This morning, the Sun rose. Did we thereby learn something new about the Solar System? No, because that is exactly what we expected. By contrast, we most definitely would have learned something new (assuming we were still around to reflect about it) if, for some extraordinary reason, the Sun HADN'T risen in the morning today.
For exactly that reason, we haven't learned all that much, in the past year, about the economic impact of the 2017 tax act. For example, there was absolutely no dispute, among serious, responsible, and knowledgeable people, that the act was going to lose a lot of revenue. And so it has - perhaps slightly on the high side, relative to "dynamic" expectations, but that is what I expected for various reasons.
We also "learned" that it did not stimulate a flood of new U.S. investment and other economic activity. But the only thing that was seriously in dispute in this dimension remains so - what might be the effects on U.S. investment over a much longer time horizon - given, e.g., that the relationship between statutory and effective tax rates for multinationals is not perfectly understood (and may have changed in multiple ways by reason of the 2017 act), and that the long-term effect of rising debt overhang will need more time to be observed.
There also seems to have been, unsurprisingly, a bit of mild Keynesian stimulus at the wrong time, i.e., when it was not really much needed. The rising debt overhang may make it harder in the future to use Keynesian stimulus through budget deficits at times when it might be far more needed.
Whether or not the flood of stock buybacks by U.S. companies was expected, it should have been. What else to do with the money that one is no longer constrained from "repatriating" as an accounting matter? And big U.S. companies with overseas profits were not generally cash-constrained with regard to U.S. investment.
The buybacks gave a great talking point to critics of the 2017 act, because their occurrence seemed so contradictory to the ridiculous talking points that were being made by the act's proponents. But were the buybacks as such bad? Not really. They presumably shifted funds from companies that had no particular current use for the $$ to shareholders who now might find it transactionally cheaper to direct as they liked the value that was paid out. This can be a good thing. And if the funds transfer was merely being delayed under prior law by international deferral, that wasn't really doing anyone any particular good (including the U.S. tax authorities).
2) International changes
I've discussed the 2017 U.S. international tax changes in greater detail on other occasions. But 3 points I made are as follows:
(a) In the aftermath of GILTI and the BEAT, it's clearer than ever that we're in a "post-territorial" world, i.e., one in which the old "worldwide versus territorial" debate has been shown to be orthogonal to the issues of main interest to policymakers.
(b) Many U.S. tax lawyers with whom I have spoken have an aesthetic dislike for the shift in U.S. international tax law, and not just because it wiped out much of their knowledge and allowed their junior associates to be on a more even knowledge footing with them, going forward. GILTI, the BEAT, and FDII (to the extent that anyone actually cares about it) have devalued legal advice based on judgment, relative to clients' running lots of scenarios to guide tax planning.
E.g., suppose the client is wondering about whether it will face the BEAT this year, rather than escaping it under the so-called 3 percent rule (under which the BEAT doesn't apply if less than 3% of one's deductions are "base erosion tax benefits"). Even if one can set the numerator for this computation with certainty - which may not be the case - one is highly unlikely to know the denominator with anything close to certainty, as it may depend on the uncertain course of various business outcomes. So rather than just ask the lawyers what the BEAT means, firms may base key planning choices on running lots of probabilistic scenarios. Whether or not this is any worse than the prior state of the play ifor American or global welfare, it's definitely much less fun for the tax lawyers.
(c) It's been interesting to observe that a number of other countries appear to be intrigued by the idea of adopting their own versions of GILTI and the BEAT. While not a huge surprise, I didn't regard this in advance as entirely certain..
3) Partial repeal of state and local tax (SALT) deductions
On this front, it's been fun (if that's the word for it) to observe the fault lines in academic debate between people who might typically agree more with each other than they do on this issue.
In the broader policymaking world, I've been at least mildly surprised by:
(a) the extent to which blue states have stepped forward to devise what might be called workarounds (I think this reflects the legislation's nasty red state vs. blue state optics).
(b) the extent to which the Treasury, in response, has seemingly been willing to back away from past limited giveaways to what were mostly red state (albeit more limited) workaround schemes. I had wondered if the Treasury might either (i) feel more constrained by past rulings that favored, e.g., the use of state law tax credit tricks to make private school tuition effectively deductible, or (ii) be willing to respond with baldfaced inconsistency as between past red state and post-2017 blue state planning responses.
4) Where might we be headed next?
This remains unclear, given both the long-term fiscal gap and pervasive U.S. political uncertainty. But future action may need to focus more on new revenue sources (such as from VATs, including disguised versions such as the BAT/DBCFT, and/or from carbon taxes and the like), and less on "tax reform."
Indeed, I think the term "tax reform" is now dead, other than as a synonym for "changes that I, the speaker, happen to like." And good riddance, as it had outlived its usefulness.
From at least the 1950s through the 1970s, "tax reform" mainly meant broadening the base so that high-end effective rates would tend to come closer to matching the era's steeply graduated statutory rates.
Then in the 1980s, "tax reform" came to mean broadening the base and lowering the rates, in a manner that was meant to be net revenue-neutral and distribution-neutral. It might also involve switching from the current income tax to a far more comprehensive version of the consumption tax, although that definition didn't really get very far off the ground until more recent decades, when it continued to lack political traction.
After the so-called 2017 "tax reform" that lost immense revenue, was extremely regressive, and in many respects narrowed the tax base (e.g., via the egregious passthrough rules), I think we can forget about the term's being used in public policymaking without evoking derisive laughter. Whether or not 1986 tax reform was tragedy (I don't think it was), 2017 was definitely farce, and this implies no third act for the concept.
We divided up in advance the particular topics to be discussed by each of us, and here is a very rough effort to reproduce in miniature my comments:
1) What have we learned in the past year about the economic impact of the 2017 tax act?
This morning, the Sun rose. Did we thereby learn something new about the Solar System? No, because that is exactly what we expected. By contrast, we most definitely would have learned something new (assuming we were still around to reflect about it) if, for some extraordinary reason, the Sun HADN'T risen in the morning today.
For exactly that reason, we haven't learned all that much, in the past year, about the economic impact of the 2017 tax act. For example, there was absolutely no dispute, among serious, responsible, and knowledgeable people, that the act was going to lose a lot of revenue. And so it has - perhaps slightly on the high side, relative to "dynamic" expectations, but that is what I expected for various reasons.
We also "learned" that it did not stimulate a flood of new U.S. investment and other economic activity. But the only thing that was seriously in dispute in this dimension remains so - what might be the effects on U.S. investment over a much longer time horizon - given, e.g., that the relationship between statutory and effective tax rates for multinationals is not perfectly understood (and may have changed in multiple ways by reason of the 2017 act), and that the long-term effect of rising debt overhang will need more time to be observed.
There also seems to have been, unsurprisingly, a bit of mild Keynesian stimulus at the wrong time, i.e., when it was not really much needed. The rising debt overhang may make it harder in the future to use Keynesian stimulus through budget deficits at times when it might be far more needed.
Whether or not the flood of stock buybacks by U.S. companies was expected, it should have been. What else to do with the money that one is no longer constrained from "repatriating" as an accounting matter? And big U.S. companies with overseas profits were not generally cash-constrained with regard to U.S. investment.
The buybacks gave a great talking point to critics of the 2017 act, because their occurrence seemed so contradictory to the ridiculous talking points that were being made by the act's proponents. But were the buybacks as such bad? Not really. They presumably shifted funds from companies that had no particular current use for the $$ to shareholders who now might find it transactionally cheaper to direct as they liked the value that was paid out. This can be a good thing. And if the funds transfer was merely being delayed under prior law by international deferral, that wasn't really doing anyone any particular good (including the U.S. tax authorities).
2) International changes
I've discussed the 2017 U.S. international tax changes in greater detail on other occasions. But 3 points I made are as follows:
(a) In the aftermath of GILTI and the BEAT, it's clearer than ever that we're in a "post-territorial" world, i.e., one in which the old "worldwide versus territorial" debate has been shown to be orthogonal to the issues of main interest to policymakers.
(b) Many U.S. tax lawyers with whom I have spoken have an aesthetic dislike for the shift in U.S. international tax law, and not just because it wiped out much of their knowledge and allowed their junior associates to be on a more even knowledge footing with them, going forward. GILTI, the BEAT, and FDII (to the extent that anyone actually cares about it) have devalued legal advice based on judgment, relative to clients' running lots of scenarios to guide tax planning.
E.g., suppose the client is wondering about whether it will face the BEAT this year, rather than escaping it under the so-called 3 percent rule (under which the BEAT doesn't apply if less than 3% of one's deductions are "base erosion tax benefits"). Even if one can set the numerator for this computation with certainty - which may not be the case - one is highly unlikely to know the denominator with anything close to certainty, as it may depend on the uncertain course of various business outcomes. So rather than just ask the lawyers what the BEAT means, firms may base key planning choices on running lots of probabilistic scenarios. Whether or not this is any worse than the prior state of the play ifor American or global welfare, it's definitely much less fun for the tax lawyers.
(c) It's been interesting to observe that a number of other countries appear to be intrigued by the idea of adopting their own versions of GILTI and the BEAT. While not a huge surprise, I didn't regard this in advance as entirely certain..
3) Partial repeal of state and local tax (SALT) deductions
On this front, it's been fun (if that's the word for it) to observe the fault lines in academic debate between people who might typically agree more with each other than they do on this issue.
In the broader policymaking world, I've been at least mildly surprised by:
(a) the extent to which blue states have stepped forward to devise what might be called workarounds (I think this reflects the legislation's nasty red state vs. blue state optics).
(b) the extent to which the Treasury, in response, has seemingly been willing to back away from past limited giveaways to what were mostly red state (albeit more limited) workaround schemes. I had wondered if the Treasury might either (i) feel more constrained by past rulings that favored, e.g., the use of state law tax credit tricks to make private school tuition effectively deductible, or (ii) be willing to respond with baldfaced inconsistency as between past red state and post-2017 blue state planning responses.
4) Where might we be headed next?
This remains unclear, given both the long-term fiscal gap and pervasive U.S. political uncertainty. But future action may need to focus more on new revenue sources (such as from VATs, including disguised versions such as the BAT/DBCFT, and/or from carbon taxes and the like), and less on "tax reform."
Indeed, I think the term "tax reform" is now dead, other than as a synonym for "changes that I, the speaker, happen to like." And good riddance, as it had outlived its usefulness.
From at least the 1950s through the 1970s, "tax reform" mainly meant broadening the base so that high-end effective rates would tend to come closer to matching the era's steeply graduated statutory rates.
Then in the 1980s, "tax reform" came to mean broadening the base and lowering the rates, in a manner that was meant to be net revenue-neutral and distribution-neutral. It might also involve switching from the current income tax to a far more comprehensive version of the consumption tax, although that definition didn't really get very far off the ground until more recent decades, when it continued to lack political traction.
After the so-called 2017 "tax reform" that lost immense revenue, was extremely regressive, and in many respects narrowed the tax base (e.g., via the egregious passthrough rules), I think we can forget about the term's being used in public policymaking without evoking derisive laughter. Whether or not 1986 tax reform was tragedy (I don't think it was), 2017 was definitely farce, and this implies no third act for the concept.
Close to publication
If I do say so myself, I've always (well, since I wrote it in 3 days, a couple of summers ago) rather liked this paper of mine, which mainly takes the form of a dialogue between two friends who disagree about the ethics of "legally defensible" tax planning by the super-rich and large corporations that might have the effects of helping to super-charge plutocracy and monopoly. It's no Socratic dialogue - the contestants are evenly matched, reflecting that I myself partially agree with each.
The article is now close to being published, as a chapter in the forthcoming Oxford University Press volume, Tax, Inequality, and Human Rights.
The article is now close to being published, as a chapter in the forthcoming Oxford University Press volume, Tax, Inequality, and Human Rights.