Yesterday, we had our Week 3 session at the Colloquium, featuring
Kim Blanchard's 's The Tax Significance of Legal Personality. This
came after we were forced to cancel our Week 2 session, concerning David
Kamin's In Good Times and Bad: Designing Legislation That Responds to FiscalUncertainty. The Kamin session was a casualty of last week's NYC Blizzard
That Wasn't, which led to NYU's being closed for the day. I will blog
here about that paper shortly.
Blanchard is at Weil Gotshal, and is a prominent leader in the NYC
tax bar. We frequently have had practitioner papers at the colloquium, although
not for the last couple of years, and it was good to get back to this
practice.
I see the paper
as making both a narrow argument and a broad argument.
The narrow
argument is that the question of whether a legal entity, such as a corporation
or partnership, is treated by a given country as having “legal personality”
should not affect its tax treatment. (While
the U.S. doesn’t even have a “legal personality” concept to speak of, in many
countries this concept not only plays a general doctrinal role, but may influence
the resolution of various tax issues – e.g., whether the entity is “opaque” and
taxed at the entity level, or “transparent” with income tax being imposed directly
on its owners.)
The paper
argues that legal personality, as used in other countries, tends either to be
meaningless and circular, or to focus on formal legal attributes, such as the
entity’s capacity to sue or be sued, that should not affect the tax analysis. This struck me as a highly persuasive
argument, subject only to the question of what people who are more familiar
than I am with non-U.S. legal and tax systems would say in response.
The broad
argument involves what one might call the ‘enry ‘iggins issue.
In My Fair Lady, Henry Higgins (known to
posterity as ‘enry ‘iggins) has a show-stopping song in which he asks: “Why
can’t a woman be more like a man?” Whereas
the paper asks: “Why can’t a European, Canadian, etc. be more like an
American?”
In My Fair Lady, of course, the joke is
that the woman (Eliza Doolittle) whom he is castigating as crazy, irrational,
upsetting, etc., is in fact much saner, wiser, kinder, more mature, more
considerate, more tolerant, and more generous than he is.
The paper
argues that U.S. tax law is generally better than that of the other countries
surveyed. Better, in that it focuses
more on economic substance and less on formalistic legal details. This, the paper argues, makes U.S. tax law
not just less manipulable by sophisticated taxpayers, but also more
predictable. For example, if a foreign
court is basing the availability of treaty benefits on an empty formal concept,
who knows how they will come out.
Whereas, in the U.S. setting, even if line-drawing issues create
uncertainty, at least we know what the issues are.
As a fellow
American, who am I to judge whether the critique is fairer of foreign tax systems
than ‘enry’s would-be critique of Eliza.
But a number of U.S. tax practitioners do indeed report that, when
discussing foreign tax law in transactional settings, they frequently are told
that one can easily get away things that, in the U.S., would be far more dubious
because our rules make some effort to look at underlying economic substance.
The paper also
argues that the U.S. check-the-box rules have been over-blamed for “hybridity”
in U.S. vs. foreign entity classification.
(Hybridity permits, for example, a U.S. company to strip income out of a
French or German affiliate into a tax haven without encountering U.S. tax liability
under subpart F.) I agree with it that the
conceptual causes of hybridity lie deeper than just our adopting check-the-box,
but its adoption – with transparent single-owner entities being wholly
disregarded (to non-international tax experts: sorry for the jargon here) – was
indeed empirically a key trigger for the explosion of post-1997 foreign tax
planning by U.S. companies. Whether this
mainly hurt countries such as France or Germany that were having their income
stripped out, or the U.S. itself, if more taxable income first traveled from
here to those countries now that it could be trans-shipped yet further, remains
an open empirical question.
In addition,
the paper argues that a key reason why the U.S., in deciding which entities
should be treated as tax-opaque, pays less heed than most peer countries to commercial
law factors, is that we have federal income tax law and state-level commercial law. (For example, one incorporates under the law
of a state, not any sort of federal incorporation statute.) While this is plausible, my own explanatory account
would focus more on the particular history of Treasury and IRS efforts to curb
effective electivity with respect to entity classification, which collapsed
under its own weight due to some early mistakes (leading ultimately to check-the-box)
and which in 1987 led to a brand-new approach, requiring publicly traded
partnerships to be treated as corporations.
In response to
the paper’s main subject matter of opaque versus transparent, I agree that
using formal concepts of “legal personality” to distinguish between entities
that should be taxed at the entity level, like U.S. C corporations, or at the
owner level, like U.S. partnerships, is likely to be unhelpful. But I’d limit any defense of current U.S. law
by making the observation that one could argue we get it close to backwards, in
deciding which entities should be taxed each way.
There are
several reasons why it matters which way one does things. Often the key point at issue, under current
U.S. law, is that corporate income is at least theoretically double-taxed. This makes little direct sense, although one
could view it as responding indirectly to the failure of the entity-level tax,
or as not worth eliminating in mid-stream given transition and revenue issues.
But leaving
aside double taxation (which is not a necessary consequences of imposing an
entity-level tax), it’s generally preferable to levy taxes at the owner level,
not the entity level, if one can do
that well enough. In cases where an
owner-level tax is sufficiently feasible, the main thing one achieves by
imposing tax at the entity level is (a) applying the wrong marginal tax rates, relative
to those of the owners, and (b) making the taxpayer’s residence more
tax-elastic. This can reduce both
efficiency, by distorting entity choice, and distributional objectives, by
creating failures to impose the desired marginal tax rate (or any positive tax
rate).
So, the basic
way I’d divide up the baby is by using entity-level taxation only in circumstances where it is too
hard to make owner-level taxation work properly.
When is it
relatively easy to make owner-level taxation work properly? I would say, (a) when ownership interests in
entities are publicly traded, causing them to have observable market prices, and
(b) when all of the ownership interests are pro rata, rather than there being a
complex deal in which there are multiple classes of equity, or some hold more
of an upside or downside for X asset or activity than Y asset or activity, and
so forth.
This offers
support for applying owner-level taxation to publicly-traded entities – the exact
opposite of the U.S. approach, under which public trading means that you are
taxed as a C corporation. Obviously,
there are other issues here (e.g., Reuven Avi-Yonah argues for taxation at the
entity level given managerial / governance issues). But among those who have argued for replacing
the entity-level corporate tax with an owner-level mark to market tax are Eric
Toder & Alan Viard, Joe Bankman, Joe Dodge, Michael Knoll, and Victor
Thuronyi. Plus, David Miller would
impose mark-to-market taxation more broadly and use some of the revenues to
lower greatly the entity-level corporate rate.
(I hope I am not leaving anyone out.)
So right or wrong in the end, the view I suggest here is surely not an
eccentric one.
Next, pro rata
versus non-pro rata deals. Even without
public trading, if an entity’s owners have a pro rata deal, it may be pretty
simple to do entity-level income computations and then flow everything through. So why bother with the entity-level tax,
which may impose the wrong marginal tax rates, unless for some reason it is
hard to find and/or tax all of the owners.
But as soon as you have a non-pro rata deal, and a gap between taxable
income and economic income, you will face a giant mess in trying to get the
owner-level allocation right. In such
cases, there is no good answer to the question of whom a tax item really
pertains to.
U.S. partnership
tax law provides for special allocations of items to particular taxpayers. This represents an effort to get the
computation logically “right” under crazy, counterfactual assumptions (e.g.,
that it’s as if the entity was being liquidated today, with taxable income
proving to equal economic income, and with eyes closed to, say, the use of
nonrecourse financing that may transfer downside risk from owners to lenders). It has led U.S. partnership tax law into a
horrendous morass of excess complexity and widespread noncompliance (I am
told), the latter from a combination of less sophisticated taxpayers throwing
up their hands and more sophisticated ones relying on audacious legal opinions. And its apparent aim of restricting
manipulability has certainly not fared well.
Suppose one got
rid of special allocations, requiring either pro rata tax allocation (as I
gather some countries do) or entity-level imposition of the tax plus an
owner-level integration method. Given
that there actually are non-pro rata economic deals, this would still get
things wrong, and I certainly can’t say with any confidence or personal knowledge
that the end result would be less
manipulable than U.S. partnership tax law (although the fact that the devil I know
is such a mess almost inclines me to believe it might be).
Anyway, put
these two together, and you could say that current U.S. tax law gets it close
to backwards. Suppose we had owner-level
mark-to-market taxation of publicly traded entities, owner-level flow-through
taxation of “simple” entities with sufficiently pro rata deals, and integrated
entity-level taxation of “complex” entities, such as those with non-pro rata
deals. That would be largely the reverse
of current U.S. law (although not entirely, since we do apply owner-level flow-through
taxation both to simple partnerships, and to electing S corporations, which
must have only one class of stock). So,
even if we are wise to ignore “legal personality” as a classification factor,
it is not clear how much better we are actually doing.
Nice Information!!
ReplyDeleteIt is very helpful information about Tax It Here. Thanks for sharing
Tax Experts
Taxes are collected on goods or services where the social cost is not reflected in the private cost.
ReplyDeleteasset protection