Yesterday at the
colloquium, David Albouy presented the above article, applying optimal tax
theory to the question of how consumption via home occupancy should be
taxed. This was welcome diversification
of the balance in our overall portfolio of articles for the semester.
I also got an
update that I shouldn’t have needed (i.e., I ought already to have been
up-to-date) regarding how Albouy has, in prior work (The Unequal Geographic Burden of Federal Taxation), modified or
corrected the view taken by Louis Kaplow (in Regional Cost of Living Adjustments in Tax/Transfer Schemes, Tax
Law Review, 1995) and Michael Knoll with Thomas Griffith (in Taxing Sunny Days: Adjusting Taxes for
Regional Cost of Living Adjustments, Harvard Law Review, 2003) who concluded that generally the income tax system ought not to take into account regional
cost of living differences.
By taking a
fuller view of how a national labor market with regional wage and price
differences operates, in the presence of a tax system that hits wages but not
amenities that are accepted in lieu of wages, Albouy finds that “workers in
cities offering above-average wages— cities with high productivity, low quality
of life, or inefficient housing sectors—pay 27 percent more in federal taxes
than otherwise identical workers in cities offering below-average wages.
According to simulation results, taxes lower long-run employment levels in
high-wage areas by 13 percent and land and housing prices by 21 and 5 percent,
causing locational inefficiencies costing 0.23 percent of income, or $28
billion in 2008. Employment is shifted from north to south and from urban to
rural areas. Tax deductions [that take account of regional cost-of-living
differences] index taxes partially to local cost of living, improving locational
efficiency.”
Thus, without
impugning the logic employed by Kaplow, Knoll, and Griffith under their
assumptions, it may be that one should adopt an opposite conclusion regarding
the bottom line question of whether the tax system ought to address regional
wage and price differences. Arguably,
the better view is that it should so adjust, due to the distortion that results
from taxing wages while not taxing the imputed income (in a broad sense) that a
low-wage region may offer at equilibrium in lieu of cash.
Anyway, on to the current article, which is closely
related to the earlier one in focusing on the regional distortions that result
from taxing cash wages but not their in-kind substitutes such as good weather. Here is an expanded version of my own
thoughts about the article. It addresses
3 topics: (1) housing and the work-leisure choice, (2) other inputs to how we
should tax housing, and (3) political economy and fiscal federalism
considerations.
(1) Housing and the work-leisure choice
Since income (and
other related) taxes hit work but not leisure, it’s theoretically agreed that,
while we should generally tax all commodities equally, this is subject to the
proviso that we should tax those that are leisure complements at a higher rate,
and those that are work complements at a lower rate, in cases where we can
identify such commodities. This has the efficiency
benefit of somewhat offsetting the tax system’s underlying discouragement of
work relative to leisure.
Less well-settled
is the question of whether there is much to gain practically by looking for
leisure complements and work complements.
But housing is a very important element of overall consumption that
clearly might have systematic relationships to this question. So not looking there would be foolish, yet little has been done on this question in previous work.
As background to
this inquiry, the current federal income tax system heavily favors home
ownership. But, on the other hand, state
and local real property taxes tend to burden home consumption relative to other
consumption. The net balance is probably
pro-home consumption, but one should keep both pieces in mind.
The article
identifies several dimensions to locational choices that might affect how we
might like to tax home consumption, in view of its interaction with the work-leisure
relationship.
(a) “Hawaii versus Manhattan” – To typify
this distinction simplistically for clarity’s sake, Hawaii offers nice weather
and beach access, which are nontaxable amenities albeit built into housing
prices. Manhattan instead offers two
distinct kinds of taxable amenities that are also built into housing
prices. The first (earning amenities) is
that you may be able earn a lot more if you live in Manhattan than in Hawaii. The second (consumer spending amenities) is
that you may be better situated to buy nice things for daily consumption if you
live in Manhattan than in Hawaii. For
example, consider all our restaurants.
(b) “Westchester versus Manhattan” – Second,
even if you work in a high-wage area with low nontaxable amenities, you can
either live near work, or else some distance from which you commute. As I’ll discuss in section (2), there are
several reasons outside the simple optimal tax model why we might take an
interest in commuting. But even just
within the basic model, the paper offers evidence suggesting that long commutes
tend to crowd out marginal work, more than marginal leisure.
The basic
argument is to tax Hawaii housing because its nontaxable amenities are a leisure
complement and a work substitute, along (perhaps more contingently) with
Westchester housing because the commuting also operates at the margin as a work
substitute, while subsidizing Manhattan housing because its two types of
amenities are work complements / leisure substitutes. You earn more instead of choosing nice
weather and the beach due to the earning amenities, and you use restaurants
instead of cooking due to the consumer spending amenities.
This argument
makes good sense to me – perhaps no surprise, given that I am a Manhattanite –
and of course it dovetails nicely with Albouy’s earlier work concerning the
unequal geographic burden of federal taxation.
One point I might add, however, is that Manhattan may differ from Hawaii
and Westchester with respect to the marginal effect on work versus leisure of
increasing one’s house size, given that one lives in a given location. In Manhattan, all you need is a roof over
your head to have a shot at realizing the earning amenities. But once you actually have a kitchen, along
with enough space to restrain the urge to go out all the time, you may start
substituting away from the consumer spending amenities. So possibly the basic optimal subsidy for the
Manhattan housing location should be supplemented by a larger marginal rate of tax
on increasing house size in Manhattan than in the other two locations.
(2) Other inputs to how we should tax
housing
The paper notes 4
main inputs to how we might want to tax housing, other than those involving the
work versus leisure choice.
(a) Positive externalities to urban agglomeration
– These might also support a Manhattan subsidy.
(b) Henry George case for a land tax on site
value – The famous Henry George argument for taxing site value (as distinct
from improvements), because land is relatively fixed and yet taxing it tends to
be progressive, is one of those things that is potentially important, generally
accepted theoretically, and yet generally ignored. It’s more important than ever in a Piketty
era – especially when it’s been argued that a lot of Piketty’s finding reflect
real estate value hikes, rather than a generalized
r > g. Even taxing site value
plus the value of improvements (i.e., housing) may retain some of the lump sum
tax elements of the pure Henry George land tax, despite its discouraging the
improvements.
(c Other commuting issues – One may also
want tax housing that is associated with commuting if commuting imposes other
social costs that for some reason cannot be taxed more directly. For example, if we fail to adopt proper
Pigovian taxes on the pollution associated with car travel, and also don’t
adopt proper congestion pricing for rush hour traffic, taxing the housing in
communities associated with such travel may be better than nothing.
In this regard,
it’s worth noting that the U.S. income tax system actually does discourage
commuting a bit. We don’t allow
commuting costs for going to one’s primary place of work, whereas some other
countries (e.g, Germany do). Purely from
the standpoint of measuring income, neither approach is fully correct.
To illustrate,
suppose Person A has a job and is choosing between two places to live, one of
them downtown with higher rent and lower commuting costs, and the other in the suburbs
with lower rent and higher commuting costs.
In this scenario, the U.S. income tax system properly disallows
commuting costs as, in effect, rent substitutes.
But suppose
Person B has a fixed home and is choosing between two jobs, one near home with
a lower wager and lower commuting costs, and the other some distance away with
a higher wage and higher commuting costs.
In this scenario, the German system, rather than the U.S. one, rightly
frames the taxpayer’s presumed marginal choice.
While I suspect
that the U.S. approach is empirically better on balance from an income measurement
perspective, the fact that the Person B scenario sometimes exists suggests that
we are “inefficiently” (all else equal) disfavoring commuting a bit, as
compared to getting it right all the time.
But this may be a good feature, rather than a bug, if we also
independently have grounds for tax-disfavoring commuting.
(d) Housing consumption by the poor –
There is probably little or no good reason for generally favoring home
consumption relative to other consumption. But if homelessness has negative
externalities (in addition to being very bad for those who face it), we may
want to subsidize housing consumption by the poor, in lieu of just giving them
enough aid to fend off homelessness.
(3) Political economy / fiscal federalism
The issues that
the paper presents regarding how to tax housing in Manhattan versus Hawaii
versus Westchester are singularly those of interest to a national-level
decision-maker – not one who is setting tax policy (even optimally from the
standpoint of residents) for any of those localities. This is of especial interest given that the
relevant tax instruments include real property taxes that are set at the state
and local levels. Obviously, these
issues belong in a wholly different paper, but given the Albouy paper they are
worth noting.
No comments:
Post a Comment