My last post
offered a rumination prompted by my teaching a class in Corporate and
International Tax Policy. This time around, the sand in the oyster (as I’d like
to think) comes from teaching Survey of U.S. International Taxation.
Yesterday in this
class, I was slogging through the main source rules in U.S. international tax
law. These are the rules that determine, for U.S. income tax purposes, whether
a given taxpayer has U.S. source income or foreign source income (FSI).
Foreign taxpayers
are potentially taxable in the U.S. only on what we classify as U.S. source
income. As for U.S. taxpayers, be they individuals or resident corporations, source
matters because they need sufficient FSI to claim all otherwise available
foreign tax credit. So U.S. taxpayers may actually not care about source determinations,
if they do not have to worry about running into the foreign tax credit
limitation. (In some settings, however, the factors that underlie source determinations
overlap with something that typically matters a lot more – whether a given increment
of income is going to be treated as U.S. source income of a U.S. entity, or FSI
of an affiliated foreign entity.)
Anyway, teaching
the source rules can be deadly for all concerned because the rules are so
tedious and empty. They follow the usual “cubbyhole” approach of tax law – you have a
bunch of categories, so for each item on your tax return you decide where to
shove it, and that determines how the source question will be handled.
For example, the source
of dividend and interest income depends (in the general case) on the residence
of the payor. Dividends and interest paid by, say, Apple or GE yield U.S.
source income, whereas those paid by, say, Tim Hortons or Siemens yield FSI.
For personal
services, source depends on where you render the services. But for rents and royalties,
it depends on where the use occurs. For sales of personal property (other than
business inventory), it generally depends on the residence of the seller. For
example, if I sell a painting the gain is U.S. source, but, if Pablo Picasso
sells it, it’s FSI.
Ho-hum. A natural
question to ask about these rules is why they come out as they do, and what they
are trying to implement or accomplish. No short answer, of course, and even the
long answers aren’t very satisfying. One of their annoying features in practice
is that, in many cases, the same thing economically can be structured to fit
into one cubbyhole or another.
A classic example
that we discussed in yesterday’s class was the Wodehouse case. Yes, that Wodehouse – Pelham Grenville, aka P.G.,
aka Plum. While Wodehouse was living in the French Riviera (and/or in German
prison camp after France fell in 1940), he wrote Uncle Fred in the Springtime – one of my absolute favorites, a
hilarious masterpiece – and also Money in the Bank, which is great fun although not quite as top-drawer for him – and sold their
North American (i.e., mainly U.S.) rights for $40,000 each. So what was the
source of his income?
Economically,
this really was income received for personal services. He sat there in his
little French cottage (or the less commodious German arrangements that followed
for him until 1945) and beavered away, so to speak, ultimately to the great joy
of his many readers. This would mean that he had FSI, not taxable by the U.S. But
as a matter of legal form this characterization had no chance.
A second view
held that he was getting royalties for the U.S. use of the intellectual
property that he had created through his labors. This was also true, unless we adopt View #3
below, and it would mean that he had U.S. source income.
A third view held
that he had sold personal property, i.e., his U.S. rights. At the time, this
would mean he’d have FSI, as a foreign national selling such property. (The law
has no changed since then, so that he would lose under this view because he was
selling a piece of the copyright, rather than other personal property.) But under tax law at the time, he would win if one regarded all of the
North American rights, but no other rights, as sufficiently an item of separate
“property” to avoid its being treated as a mere advance sale of royalties. Obviously, whenever one sells property that will yield expected rents or
royalties, one is in effect selling them in one lump, and yet in some cases
this works as a matter of tax characterization – e.g., to create capital gains
rather than ordinary income, where that is the issue presented. (The inevitably unsatisfying line-drawing cases here assess when capital gains "carve-outs" will work for tax purposes versus not working.)
What are all these source rules even
about? The framework I came up with, for purposes of trying to make it more than just a list, involved the distinction between origin-based and destination-based
rules for carving up the tax base when there are multi-jurisdictional
transactions.
Suppose initially
that you have just one jurisdiction and no cross-border trade. So everything
produced there is also consumed there. Each item’s point of origin – where it
was produced – is the same as its point of destination – where it was consumed.
Leaving aside the intertemporal issues raised by the choice between income
taxation and consumption taxation, it makes no difference whether one taxes everything
on the origin basis or the destination basis. The source of each item is the
same either way.
Now suppose we
allow for cross-border trade. Individuals who live in the jurisdiction now can
swap some of their production for others’ production. Given trade’s
reciprocity, the value of what they produce still equals (in market terms) the
value of what they get to consume. But
tax bases defined, in source terms, using the origin basis and the destination basis
tax bases no longer include exactly the same items. Exports but not imports are
treated as domestic source via the origin basis, while imports not exports are
treated as domestic source via the destination basis.
The equivalence
underlies standard thinking about international trade. For example, export
subsidies are pretty much the same as import tariffs. And this often has tax
policy implications. For example, a destination-basis VAT is not distorting
trade by reason of its exempting exports and taxing imports. By contrast, an
origin-basis income tax that departs from its standard approach by including targeted
export subsidies is getting just what it deserves when the World Trade
Organization strikes down the subsidies.
How do the source
rules relate to this? To some extent, they can be divided into those that are (at
least kind of) origin basis, and those that are destination basis.
The rule that the
source of dividend and interest income depends on the residence of the issuer
makes these what I would call fake origin-basis rules. They’re origin basis in
the sense that where the money came from – the residence of the counterparty
that paid it to you, i.e., where it “originated” or the use of the underlying
funds occurred – determines the source. What makes these rules only fake origin-basis
is that there are need not actually be any significant connection connection
between the payor’s formal residence (e.g., as a legal entity) and any actual set
of facts about where the associated use of the underlying funds occurred.
The rule for
personal services is clearly an origin-based rule. Wodehouse wrote his comic
masterpieces in England and then France (before moving ultimately to Long
Island), so that’s where the production occurred, and then his work was
exported to the U.S. among other markets.
The rule for rent
and royalties is, by contrast, a destination-based rule. Revenues from consumer
use under the U.S. copyright to Uncle
Fred in the Springtime would face a well-designed destination-basis U.S.
VAT, but would not face income taxation here if we relied on where the production
activity occurred.
Finally, the rule
for sales of personal property is probably best-viewed as origin-based, insofar
as it’s actually one or the other. It looks at the person who sold the
property, and who thus perhaps “produced” the gain from sale (even if only in
the sense of picking something that would appreciate in value). In a
Wodehouse-type case, of course, this is especially clear, as he actually
created the property that he is selling through his personal efforts.
It’s a truism
that, for reasons I’ve discussed elsewhere, an income tax pretty much has to
use the origin basis as its main method, whereas a consumption tax can use either the origin-basis
or the destination-basis. But
nonetheless real world income taxes often use destination-basis rules, such as when
determining the source of income from cross-border transactions. A good example,
apart from certain of the source rules that I’ve discussed above, is the use of
sales factors in formulary apportionment. These cause a business that is active
in multiple jurisdictions to be taxed, in a given jurisdiction, based at least
partly on its sales to consumers and others in that jurisdiction.
Why does the
U.S., along with other countries in their source rules, build as much
destination basis as it does into its source rules? Well, suppose initially we
were thinking of this in a standard international trade context. Here it’s a
bit like having an import tariff, on top of taxing domestic production even
when exported. Import tariffs can be domestically popular, as a political
matter, even when they’re good policy. But they can actually be good policy,
from the standpoint of residents’ economic welfare, where the jurisdiction has
market power, e.g., because importers would be enjoying rents (in the economic
sense, as distinct from that of “rents and royalties” under the source rules).
So one isn’t surprised to see, say, the U.S. adopting rules that might permit
it to tax P.G. Wodehouse on his work in that French Riviera cottage, given that
it led to the situation where U.S. consumers would pay for the reader’s privilege
(at zero extra marginal production cost to him).
Does our mix between
origin-basis and destination-basis source rules mean that we are effectively imposing
tariffs on certain imports? Perhaps in some cases, but my sense of the rules’
overall tenor is somewhat different, for three main reasons.
First, destination-basis
rules tend to apply to outbound as well as inbound transactions. Computer
engineers in California who design IP to generate rents and royalties abroad
would therefore be generating FSI even without access to the full panoply of
tax planning tricks that have flourished in the last couple of decades.
Second, to the
extent that different countries measure source consistently, the importer’s domestic
source income under a destination-basis rule will be FSI in the exporting
country. In such a case, the latter country may offer exemption or foreign tax
credits that eliminates “double taxation” (or, more meaningfully, combined
relative over-taxation).
Third, by
structuring carefully, taxpayers have considerable ability to decide which rule
will apply to their business income. Add in all the other tax planning
opportunities that they have, and “stateless income” may loom considerably larger
as an issue than tariffs. Indeed, even just the ability to choose between
origin-based and destination-based rules may significantly move the effective
overall regime in that direction.
Dealing with Dukhon Taxes would be an excellent experience. The very first needed only a phone discussion and it was totally free. International Tax Individual Assistance
ReplyDeleteIR35 operates by permitting the actual HMRC examiner to visualize the actual written agreement that is available between your employee as well as their clients and ensure the real nature in the working- connection is used to create a notional agreement.ir35 calculator site
ReplyDeleteDPS Accounting Solutions continues to be the best option you might have. We allow you to streamline your daily life minimizing your fiscal publicity https://www.dpsaccounting.com.au/payroll-bookkeeping-perth/, being a 1-cease-shop for your accounting requirements.
ReplyDelete