Tuesday, May 15, 2007

Tax break for managers of private investment funds

There's been much controversy lately about the tax break for managers of private investment funds that is currently under review by the Senate Finance Committee. The basics, first brought to general public attention (and certainly mine) by U of Illinois law prof Victor Fleischer, who presented his paper on the subject at the 2006 NYU Tax Policy Colloquium, are as follows. Managers of these funds typically get a standard return equaling 2% annually of the money they are managing plus 20% of the capital gain they eventually generate. The former is taxed as ordinary income, but the latter is taxed as capital gain. As Victor pointed out, this means that much of the managers' labor income is being taxed at 15% rather than 35%, even though these are some of the highest-paid people in the U.S. today.

Economically speaking, the managers' 20% return is a mix of labor income and a risky return to saving. The reason they get compensated so richly for playing with other people's money is that they are at least believed to have the ability to make big bucks, such that the investors are happy even after giving away the "2 and 20." It would be pure labor income if the managers could lock in and be paid the expected value of the 20% interest right up front. (This is of course unfeasible on measurement and liquidity grounds along with its incentive effects on what the manager does.) But even for the true investment component keep in mind that they are getting the tax benefit of deferral until sale.

What are these funds doing, exactly? While I know nothing first-hand, I gather that they run the gamut from (a) the straight hedge fund that figures out clever strategies to exploit market inefficiencies and generate above-market risk-adjusted returns to (b) takeover firms that find under-performing companies and restructure them to be more profitable, and thus rapidly salable for a big turnover profit.

Economically speaking, (b) is generally more valuable to the economy than (a). While (a) may increase market efficiency, the private return from figuring out how to beat out other investors by buying and selling at just the right time exceeds the social return. Not that I have any problem with such activity, but it definitely doesn't need to be subsidized.

By contrast, (b) may have some broader social payoffs, although the question here, from the standpoint of incentives, is whether there are positive externalities - i.e., gain beyond that captured by the entrepeneurs who sell for a big turnover profit. Note also that one would be less bullish about this activity if the improved performance came, say, from improved tax planning strategies or the one-shot gain from implicitly reneging on deferred compensation arrangements with rank and file workers, rather than from, say, rationalizing production and marketing processes.

I raise these broader issues of the social value associated with particular types of economic activity, although often one can and should ignore such issues in setting tax policy, because incentive arguments are important to the debate concerning the taxation of the 20% carried interest. The incentive case for giving managers a low tax rate is limited to some portion of the activity in category (b), although even for the best case scenario it is unclear why we should expect substantial positive externalities, i.e., social returns that aren't captured by the remake artists who make so much money for having done such a good job. I'd certainly like to think that I create value when I publish or teach. And lots of other workers in our economy can say the same. But presumably I'm paid for the value I create, and I am sadly unconvinced that I can make a powerful case for applying a lower tax rate to myself than the one that everyone else bears.

A week or two ago, the Wall Street Journal published an editorial, unless it was an op-ed (what's the difference most of the time in the WSJ these days?) arguing against making the managers pay the ordinary 35% rate. What a surprise. No comment needed. But today the Los Angeles Times published an editorial to the same effect. I figure that this is a bit more noteworthy since it wasn't as crushingly obvious that the Times would take this tack. Hence, worth a response.

I did not find the editorial very persuasive. After inaccurately describing the tax break as for takeover firms, rather than for the broader category of private investment firms, it rolls out the usual hardware about enterpeneurship and risk-taking and creating jobs and how crucial all this is to the health of the economy. The main problem with this argument, other than the poor fit between the affected firms and the claimed external social benefit, is the poor fit between the capital gains preference and the aim of addressing risk-taking.

A flat rate tax system with full loss refundability at the generally applicable marginal rate would not discourage risk-taking. Even the positive expected tax on the risk premium could be offset by investing on a riskier pre-tax basis in order to get where one wants after-tax. Since we don't have such a system, the tax system actually does discourage risk-taking, which is unfortunate, even without an externalities story, as it imposes deadweight loss beyond that implicit in taxing productive economic activity. For the big-time entrepeneurs, graduated marginal rates, although they discourage risk-taking, are not very important. These guys are way into the top bracket anyway. What matters a lot more is loss nonrefundability, in particular at the business (as opposed to the investor) level. That is, companies pay tax on profits, but do not get any tax benefit from net losses if they don't at some point have sufficient profits from other operations. A recent paper by Alan Auerbach, presented at the 2007 NYU Tax Policy Colloquium (see here) suggests that this problem is growing increasingly important.

The obvious solution to that problem is greater loss refundability. But this involves a dilemma. The one good reason for nonrefundability is to limit the tax benefit from phony tax losses. But if you can't measure income accurately, then distinguishing between the real losses that we want to allow and the phony ones that we still want to limit is tricky indeed. So, while we may not be at the optimum today, especially if (as Auerbach's paper suggests) the problem of real losses is growing more important due to a change in business dynamics, it's unclear exactly where we ought to go.

But a special capital gains rate for some set of investment fund managers is very poorly focused indeed on this underlying problem.

The L.A. Times op-ed admits that the effectiveness of using capital gains rates to encourage socially valuable entrepeneurship is "open to some debate." However, the only response it deems appropriate is "a simpler tax code that defines clearly the behavior it is trying to encourage." Big internal contradiction here. A simpler tax code would not result from trying to define the true value-creating entrepeneurs, e.g., those who are enough by way of making companies more profitable rather than merely outguessing the market by five minutes. That would undoubtedly be a complicated rule, inevitably drawing various objective bright lines about control percentage, ownership period, etc., that would further distort economic behavior and benefit mainly the accountants and lawyers who were in charge of making sure that particular investments qualified for the low rate. Almost certainly a bad idea.

There actually is one good rationale for the capital gains preference. It relates to lock-in, or the tax discouragement of selling appreciated capital assets, given that one can avoid the current tax by continuing to hold them. In view of this problem, a capital gains preference can actually raise revenue relative to full taxation, although I gather (from my memory of disputes and dueling revenue estimates from the time of the Bush I Administration) that the revenue-maximizing rate is more likely to be in the range of about 30% rather than 15%. (Although note that the optimal rate is likely to be lower than the revenue-maximizing rate.)

Anyway, this rationale seems singularly inapplicable to the investment fund managers if the stuff their firms hold is generally likely, in keeping with their business model, to be turned over quickly in any event, and if the investors in the funds, who get the remaining 80% of the turnover profits, are indeed getting the capital gains rate.

Bottom line: the Senate Finance Committee should press ahead with some version of its proposal, although I suppose Bush will just veto it anyway.

7 comments:

Anonymous said...

We should be clear, though, that hedge fund managers, for example, aren't getting the benefit of the 15% long-term capital gains rate if, as you say, the stuff their firms hold is "turned over quickly in any event." They would still have to hold their assets for over a year to get the benefit of the reduced rate on the gains from the sale of those assets.

Daniel Shaviro said...

Fair enough. I would assume they generally hold for at least a year for this reason.

An interesting sub-issue here, probably not important but I wouldn't know, goes to the question of to what extent the hedge fund managers optimize the investors' tax consequences. In big mutual funds, there's evidence that the managers are surprisingly indifferent to holders' tax planning objectives. I would think that the typical private investment fund with big-player investors offers better customer service in this regard. If there was an agency problem, however, then the current capital gain regime would better align the interests of the manager & investors because they'd be in the same position. Give the manager ordinary income that is realized upon sale and you potentially (a) make the manager not care as much about holding for at least a year, and (b) make the manager more eager than the investors to defer realization, since he'll be taxed on it at 35% not 15%. But again, perhaps none of this really matters much on the ground.

Anonymous said...

Many hedge fund managers are very active traders and everyone understands that they will be allocated short-term capital gains and losses. Many are active in the credit markets and everyone understands that there will be a lot of ordinary income allocated. Generally, though, since the manager's carry receives the same treatment as the taxable investors' gain, they have every incentive to be tax efficient. Of course, with the bigger and more successful funds, you may have nothing but U.S. tax exempts as investors.

Andrew Oh-Willeke said...

Hedge fund managers are, of course, uniquely qualified to defer realization of income until the capital gains rate applies, while securing a different economic effect through the total portfolio of transactions for the hedge fund.

Also, given the accuracy with which the value of hedge fund portfolios can be determined, because they are dealing in publicly traded securities and commodities, why shouldn't a mark to market regime be appropriate?

Anonymous said...

This tax scheme primarily benefits private equity structures not hedge funds.

Hedge fund managers generally take their 20% at the end of the year and the 20% is computed under a mark to market structure for determining what is profit and subject to 20% incentive fee.

Private equity structures - the incentive fee is collected only on a cash realization and is normally subject to hold backs/claw backs.

Anonymous said...

In my earlier comment the realization, mark to market ect terms are not tax terms but terms under the hedge fund docs.

Anonymous said...

Property Owners and Business Owners
Refinance Today or Buy Building today for what your paying Rent.
Direct Wholesale Lenders WE ARE IN 48 STATES
WE have all of your commercial and residential needs!!!
I can assist you in submitting a Fast Loan file for Fast Funding.
FAST Same day Pre Qualification and Quick Quote Call 303-921-8193

WANTED Commercial Mortgage Investor
Partner with us Venture Capital Group.

Residential:
UP TO 100% FULL DOC!!! 95% STATED!!!

Commercial:
UP TO 90%!!!

Multi-Family 5+
Office buildings
Shopping Centers
Mixed Use
Auto Repair shops
Hotel/Motel
Warehouse
Self Storage
Day Care
Mobile Home Parks
Much, Much more!!

Call now and let's close that COMMERCIAL loan for you!!
I can assist you in submitting a fast loan file and Fast Funding.
Account Executive Paul RunningHorse Vigil 303-921-8193
Email: paul.vigil@comcast.net www.capitalvigilfundingdept.com
ALL CASH BUYER of REAL ESTATE Properties any Type or Condition.

WANTED Commercial Mortgage Investor
Partner with us Venture Capital Group.

Private or Institutional Hard Money Lender wanted for our Hard Money Lending Department. That will lend to Commercial Property Owner(s) that have Large Equity in their property. The Owner Borrower(s) have Low (FICO) Credit Score(s) on their credit report. The Yield for investor lender(s) on theses type of commercial mortgages is typically higher. We will need your underwriting guild lines, in what states and the type of properties you will lend on, your turn around funding time. We have many types of Commercial properties through out 48 states in our pipe line ready to be delivered the right lender that will do FAST FUNDING. Call Paul Direct at 303-921-8193
Account Executive Paul RunningHorse Vigil 303-921-8193
Email: paul.vigil@comcast.net www.capitalvigilfundingdept.com
ALL CASH BUYER of REAL ESTATE Properties any Type or Condition.