Here is Part 2 of an adapted version of my notes for
yesterday’s session discussing David Gamage’s “A Framework for Analyzing the
Optimal Choice of Tax Instruments.”
2. THE PAPER’S ARGUMENT FOR USING MULTIPLE
TAX INSTRUMENTS
Again, the paper suggests using all of a labor income tax,
VAT, capital income tax, wealth tax, legal rules, plus perhaps more (subject to
administrative costs) to address distributional issues. But the argument is based on avoidance costs
– not on how distributional outcomes should relate to underlying “true”
information about, say, individuals’ ability, earnings, savings, or gratuitous
transfers.
One can explain the paper’s main argument in two
complementary ways. First, suppose that
potentially useful tax instruments tend to have a rising marginal cost of
public funds (MCPF) as we start using them more. MCPF is basically deadweight loss per dollar
of revenue raised, adjusted for the social value or disvalue that is associated
with a given outcome’s effect on after-tax distribution. As you use any instrument more, the ratio of
deadweight loss to revenue will tend to increase. For example, doubling the tax rate may tend
to quadruple the distortion. Likewise,
increasing audit rates, if the potential audits are ranked by expected payoff, means
adding ever less fruitful new targets. Keeping
distribution constant, the aim is to equalize the ratio of deadweight loss to
revenue raised at the margin for all instruments.
Second, and more distinctively, the paper distinguishes what
it calls single-instrument vs. multiple-instrument tax avoidance. Here the focus is on taxpayer actions to
reduce tax liability. This could involve,
for example, reducing your labor supply, altering your mix of consumption or
investment choices, or paying lawyers and accountants to work their magic for
you.
Tax avoidance presumably has rising marginal costs per dollar
of tax avoided. For example, working
(and thus earning) just a bit less than you’d prefer, taxes aside is not so
bad, but working and earning a lot less starts to get really painful. Or, the tax planners get the low-hanging
fruit first, but then it keeps getting costlier to avoid the next dollar of tax
liability.
With a continuous function for tax avoidance, you keep going
until you disvalue at exactly $1 the cost of avoiding another $1 in taxes. Let’s call that the satiation point.
Suppose there is just 1 tax instrument with a 40 percent
rate on whatever it might be (wages, Haig-Simons income, consumer spending, wealth,
etc.). Any time you lower the tax base
by $1, you save 40 cents of tax. So you
reach the satiation point when it costs you 40 cents (in utility terms) to get
a dollar out of the tax base.
Now suppose instead there are 2 tax instruments, each with a
20 percent rate. Multi-instrument
avoidance reduces them both, so the government’s shift to two distinct tax
instruments has no effect. But suppose
some avoidance techniques work on only one of the two systems. For example, a loss-creating tax shelter works
against the actual income tax, but not against a typical VAT. Then you reach the satiation point at 20
cents, instead of 40.
Where only single-instrument avoidance is feasible, multiple
tax instruments turn tax avoidance into a costly retail exercise, rather than a
cheap wholesale exercise. The result,
less tax avoidance, is unambiguously good within the paper’s assumptions. What is more, absent an offsetting concern
about tax overhead costs, there would be no obvious limit to how many separate
systems this analysis suggests that we should have.
In my view, this analysis logically holds together. However, the paper’s interpretation of it as
suggesting more specifically that we should use all of a labor income tax, VAT,
capital income tax, wealth tax, etc., puts me in mind of the following three
issues:
(1) Information versus evidence – Note two distinguishable
types of issues in tax system design.
First, what is relevant information that should affect tax liability? Second,
how as a technological matter do we get at that information? What evidence can we use to measure it?
By information, I mean something that we want to affect tax liability. Examples might include labor income and, more
controversially, returns to saving. By evidence,
I mean something that we use to get at the underlying information.
David cites a paper by Roger Gordon and Soren Nielson that considers a VAT and
cash-flow income tax that are assumed to have identical behavioral and
distributional consequences when accurately applied, but involving different
means of avoidance. You avoid the VAT
through cross-border shopping. You avoid
the consumed income tax by concealing receipts.
As is well-known in the tax policy literature, either receipts (sources
of income) or consumer spending (uses of income) can be employed towards measuring
consumption. Gordon and Nielson show
that it’s plausible one would want to use some of each instrument, so that
taxpayers can’t avoid the entire tax along either tax planning dimension.
In this model, the VAT and the consumed income tax both seek
to rely on the same information (i.e. how much was consumed), but use different
evidence. By contrast, a realization-based
income tax, a VAT, and an estate & gift tax (to name three well-known types
of tax system) differ in the information
that they treat as relevant, not just in the evidence they use. The VAT bases liability on consumption, the income
tax aims to reach work plus saving, and the estate and gift tax aims at the
making of gratuitous transfers (which implies underlying work and saving).
In theory, there is a
right answer as to the extent to which tax liability should depend on these different
types of information. That right answer ought
to be implemented as to the overall
tax system, without regard to separate instruments. (And yes, I recognize that the relevant information
might be viewed merely as evidence of something else still, such as ability or
opportunity or expected marginal utility of a dollar).
The mark-to-market
income tax, VAT, and estate & gift tax may also, quite distinctly, use
different types of evidence that invite different avoidance mechanisms. For example, the realization-based income tax
encourages strategic trading (hold the winners, sell the losers). For the VAT, there’s unreported cross-border
shopping. The estate and gift tax
obviously has a slew of avoidance techniques of its own, but also permits the
tax authority to take a one-time in-depth view of everything that the taxpayer has
on hand at death.
Suppose you like the different evidence but not the different
information. For example, you might like
taxing estates as a backup to the income tax (both for fraud problems and the
holding of appreciated assets). But that
would imply a different design for the estate tax than if you actually want tax
liability to depend on bequests as an end in itself.
One last point about information: the existing income tax
deliberately uses some types of information other than about income. Examples include the itemized deductions for
home mortgage interest and charitable contributions, along with the exclusion
for employer-provided health insurance. While
the paper groups these items with other tax avoidance, they are in fact meant
by the policymakers to affect tax liability. In principle, if allowing them is the right
policy, we would want to hold constant when using multiple instruments.
The paper notes that, in practice, such items may often be
bad policy, and that the predilection to use particular ones seems oddly
instrument-specific. For example, VATs
but not income taxes commonly offer reduced tax rates for food.
Is using more instruments likely to increase or reduce the political
tendency to make bad choices regarding the use of information to affect tax
liability? The answer to this question
is certainly far from clear.
(2) What is an instrument? – The paper defines “tax
instruments” as any policy variable that a government might adjust to raise
revenue or affect distribution. Sometimes,
however, “instrument” seems to connote instead formally distinct systems. But you can have multiple instruments in the
same system. An example would be
diversifying income tax audit selection techniques to reflect, say, both omissions
suggested by counter-party reporting and “lifestyle audits” of people who
appear to be doing quite well but haven’t reported commensurate income.
No comments:
Post a Comment