Yesterday
at the colloquium, Li Liu of the IMF presented her paper (co-authored with her
colleague Ruud de Mooij), At a Cost: The Real Effects of Transfer Pricing Regulations. This paper finds interesting and significant results
regarding the play-out when certain EU countries, between 2006 and 2014,
adopted tougher and more fully specified rules regarding transfer pricing by
multinational companies (MNCs). I found the results credible, both intuitively
and in terms of how the paper reached them, although the authors would be the
first to agree that, because this is a fairly novel research area, more work is
needed to see if similar results arise using different periods and data sets.
I'll
offer comments on it here in three buckets: the model it uses, several of its
main empirical results, and international tax policy takeaways.
1.
THE MODEL
Suppose
an MNC is deciding whether to add marginal real investment (e.g., buildings,
factories, offices, or stores, whether owned or rented) in a given country
where it already has some sort of physical presence. In a standard economic
model, this depends on the marginal investment's expected after-tax return
(treating, let us say, the MNC as risk-neutral).
If
productive inputs would be needed with respect to using the marginal real
investment, then one choice the MNC faces is whether to acquire such inputs (a)
in-house, or (b) from third parties. Absent tax considerations, this might be a
fairly straightforward analysis. But once we have source-based taxation that
makes use of transfer pricing under the arm’s length standard, things
complexify a bit. Use of a cross-border affiliate permits the MNC to engage in
profit-shifting, via the use of a transfer price that is either “too high” (if
the source country’s tax rate exceeds that of the affiliate’s country) or “too
low” if it’s the other way around.
The
more aggressive the transfer price – at least, if it is too high, and one is
profit-shifting OUT of, not into, the particular source jurisdiction – the
greater the chance that it will be challenged by the local tax authorities. In
the model, this triggers two kinds of costs: (a) the chance of a penalty,
including via the ultimate selection of a transfer price less favorable than
the MNC could have gotten away with had it been less aggressive, and (b) its
triggering extra compliance costs, such as from mass document production or
paying experts to support one’s position. So there is in principle an optimal
level of aggressiveness here.
Suppose
that the country initially just had a vague and general “arm’s length”
requirement in its substantive law. But then it adopts more detailed
substantive transfer pricing regulations (TPR) that specify particular methods,
etc.
Focusing
for now just on the outbound profit-shifting, the MNC may now find that the
optimal level of aggressiveness in its transfer pricing has declined. So it
will now expect to face a higher domestic tax liability (including from
compliance costs) than before TPR was adopted. It might even switch from using
in-house to third party suppliers for some of the productive inputs, but this
would only mitigate the expected cost, not make things as wonderful as they
were pre-TPR (given that it had previously been using affiliates).
By
lowering the expected after-tax return from the marginal investment (or
equivalently in the model, increasing the cost of capital), the adoption of TPR
would be expected to reduce marginal real investment in the jurisdiction.
As
we will see, an important further aspect of the model is that TPR might also
constrain inbound profit-shifting from higher-tax jurisdictions. Even though
the source country’s tax auditors are unlikely to pose angry challenges to
inbound profit-shifting, which increases domestic tax revenues, I presume that
the idea here is that, by specifying the applicable rules, TPR restrains what
the MNC is able to do in this dimension, consistently with following the new
rules. Therefore, and I’ll return to this below as it’s an important point, TPR
is assumed to have what I call two-sided, not just one-sided, effects. (It
would be one-sided if it only restricted outbound profit-shifting.) The data
appear to confirm that this is actually happening.
With
two-sided transfer pricing effects, the adoption of TPR need not be a
revenue-raiser even if the MNC’s real activity choices are unaffected thereby.
But with the adverse effect on the expected after-tax return from the marginal
real investment (which might be increased by reduced ability to use it for
inbound profit-shifting from higher-tax jurisdictions), one would expect the
rate of new real investment in the jurisdiction by the MNC to decline. The
paper’s main, but not only, research question is: Does it indeed decline, and
if so, then by how much?
Why
would the country care if marginal real investment by the MNC declines? While
leaving for further discussion below the question of what the country’s full
policy aims might be, the paper’s answer is that this might negatively affect
positive productivity spillovers that would accrue to the benefit of the
country’s residents.
This
answer appears to invite (although it does not require) thinking in terms of a
conventional two-factor production model (capital plus labor) in which real
investment increases local workers’ productivity, and thereby their wages. But
often talk of inbound MNC investment focuses on potential knowledge spillovers.
More on that distinction shortly.
In
terms of thinking about the model’s real-world application, I would add or
emphasize the point that often, the relevant MNCs are earning global rents or
quasi-rents (from now on, I’ll just say “rents,” for concision) by reason of
their valuable intellectual property (IP). Given that the IP already exists,
marginal real investment in the jurisdiction is likely only to earn a normal or
routine return, at least in terms of its own productive contribution to the
process.
Consider,
for example, a pharma company producing one of its hot new products at a
production facility in a tax haven. The value lies in the patent, and likely
not much (if at all) in any of the production facility’s (or its managers’ and
workers’) distinctive attributes. Thus, in a true arm’s length negotiation
between the pharma company and a third party producer, the latter would likely
only be able to capture a normal or routine return.
Ditto
for Starbucks operating coffee shops in a given country (which I discuss a bit
in my new paper that is nominally or partly about digital service taxes).
Whatever large profits the Starbucks global group may be able to rake in by
reason of its having, say, a shop every 50 feet (it can almost seem) in London,
the value isn’t being added by the local drudges who manage and work in the
facility. If Starbucks mainly used franchising in lieu of company-owned stores
(and could do this without hurting the brand), you can bet they would extract
what they could from the third party franchisees, leaving the latter with only
normal or routine returns.
But
once we have transfer pricing between affiliated entities, and in the absence
of any global consensus that MNC profits should be taxed purely in the true
production countries – which is not necessarily where the MNCs have located
their IP for tax purposes! – the countries in which these routine production
facilities have been placed may have an opportunity to capture some of the
rents, under the (probably false) premise that the MNC would have had to share
these with the local affiliate, despite its likely quite modest contribution to
true value and profitability.
Back
to the model and the MNC’s marginal real investment decision: adding such
investment in the country might often reasonably be viewed as (a) offering only
a modest pretax boost to profitability, since the real assets are likely to
earn just a normal return so far as their contribution is concerned, (b)
allowing the MNC through aggressive transfer pricing – like Starbucks’ in the
UK – to claim zero or even negative taxable income in the country, if it likes,
and (c) allowing the country, if it more assertively takes on the transfer
pricing challenge, to use it as a vehicle for taxing some of the MNC’s global
rents.
With
TPR allowing the government to do some of this that is tied to the level of the
MNC’s real investment in-country, I think it can usefully be thought of as akin
to the case in which local tax profits depend partly on the use of
property-based formulary apportionment (FA). Property-based FA operates
somewhat like a property tax, except that the local percentage of the MNC’s
global property is then applied to global profits that include rents, wherever
one thinks they were “actually” created or realized.
Just
like TPR as modeled in the paper, property-based FA is two-sided. It can shift
profits either into the country or out of it, compared to a method in which
true productive contributions were being taxed in the places where they “truly”
happened. And TPR as modeled in the paper, just like property-based FA, can
mean that inbound real investment carries a property tax-like domestic tax
price in the form of having greater domestic tax profits that are not
necessarily linked to the marginal real investment’s true (and presumably
merely normal or routine) contribution to the MNC’s global profits.
2. MAIN EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The
paper is based on studying EU data from the years 2006-2014. During this
period, 6 countries introduced transfer pricing regulations (TPR) within the
paper’s criteria. All of these countries were fairly small: Bosnia &
Herzevogina, Finland, Greece, Luxembourg, Norway, and Slovenia. This raises
questions regarding the findings’ more general applicability when larger EU
countries – say, the UK (for the moment), France, and Germany – or other
countries that are one or both of large and non-EU make similar changes.
That
said, the paper’s main empirical results include the following:
a) The average TPR adoption reduced
MNCs’ marginal rate of inbound investment by 11 percent. What is more, the MNCs appear to be investing
just as much worldwide as they would
have absent TPR’s adoption, suggesting that marginal investments are being
shifted to other countries, not reduced. The paper further finds that purely
domestic businesses do not appear to be offsetting the reduction in inbound MNC
investment by picking up the slack themselves.
Comment:
This lives up to the paper’s title – suggesting that TPR comes “at a cost” even
if one wants to raise revenue and reduce profit-shifting. But I will return
below to the question of how one might think about the relationship between
marginal real investment and positive productivity spillovers, given that this
may depend on knowledge inflows, as much or more as on the application of a
standard capital plus labor production model.
b) TPR’s effects on marginal real
investment, as well as on other things such as reported domestic profits, are
much greater if the adopting countries also have thin capitalization rules (TCR)
than if they don’t.
Comment:
This is both plausible and interesting. It suggests that MNCs use transfer
pricing and the sorts of intra-group interest flows that TCR can address as
substitutes for each other. Hence, countries that want to address
profit-shifting need to consider broad-ranging, integrated approaches – as to
which, of course, they also need to think about the full range of likely
effects.
c) TPR appears significantly to
reduce reported domestic tax profits, and thereby tax revenues (under constant
statutory corporate income tax rates) in low-tax countries. In high-tax
countries, there was a smaller finding of reduced profits and tax revenues, but
it lacked statistical significance.
Comment:
An issue about the paper’s distinction between high-tax and low-tax countries
concerns the small group of 6 (themselves small) EU countries that adopted TPR
during the period under study. This implies just 3 countries in each group
(although a given country’s status as high-tax or low-tax may have differed as
between years), and one wonders also about the classification metric.
Luxembourg, for example, has a reputation for being lower-tax in practice, and
deliberately so, than one might have thought from merely consulting its
statutory rate. And even if the other 5 countries weren’t trying as hard to be
accommodating to MNCs, issues of their (possibly either low or heterogeneous)
capacity to audit effectively might affect what status they really ought to
have in this regard.
Explaining
this result – especially given finding (d), which I’ll discuss next – appears
to require placing some weight on the two-sided character of TPR changes.
Low-tax countries would have in particular the prospect of revenue loss from
reduced inbound profit-shifting. And that’s one of only two mechanisms to
explain the finding – the other, of course, being reduced inbound investment by
reason of TPR’s adoption.
If
we fully accept this result, it’s potentially pretty decisive in its impact on
the question of whether, from a unilateral national welfare standpoint, a
country like the 6 in the study ought to push ahead and adopt TPR. Losing
revenue while ALSO marginally discouraging inbound real investment does not
sound like a great step forward.
d) Adopting TPR causes what the paper
calls the “TPR-adjusted corporate income tax rate” to be 23% higher. This is not a finding about post-TPR effective tax
rates. Rather, it concerns MNCs’ sensitivity to the statutory rate. Apparently,
for such purposes it’s as if this rate has increased by 23% of its pre-TPR
level, presumably given that outbound profit-shifting (if desired) is now
harder to accomplish than it had been previously.
Thinking
about this finding in conjunction with finding (c) suggests to me that TPR may
significantly increase expected compliance costs. After all, why act as if the
rate were now 23% higher if one isn’t actually going to be reporting more
profits and paying higher taxes? The relationship I suggest here may not be
entirely certain, but would make it easier to explain why an MNC might be
reporting lower profits, paying lower taxes, and yet being more averse than
previously to the unchanged statutory rate.
3. MAIN POLICY TAKEAWAYS
Two
in particular occur to me:
a) The “at a cost” framing and
empirical takeaway (from reduced inbound real investment) fits well into my
general normative framework these days for thinking about international tax
policy – which is that countries face a host of what I call “Goldilocks
issues.” The little girl in the
Three Bears fairytale liked her porridge best if it was “just right,” rather
than too hot or too cold. Likewise, countries that are setting their policy at
a number of different margins – e.g., how to tax inbound investment from MNCs
that may be more tax-elastic than purely domestic businesses, how to tax
outbound investment by resident MNCs, and how much outbound profit shifting by
MNCs to tolerate – often don’t have a clear right answer at a given 1-or-zero
pole. Rather, tradeoffs place them somewhere in the middle, although
unfortunately “just right” is likely to be harder to find than it was in the
fairytale for Goldilocks herself.
Revenue-raising
TPR that reduces inbound real investment would very plausibly raise exactly
these sorts of tradeoffs and intermediate solutions. So I welcome empirical
research that may help us in evaluating tradeoffs, and indeed in understanding
what they are.
b) Adopting TPR looks like it was a
bad idea in the particular circumstances that the paper examines. But that
might crucially depend on its two-sided character, rather than on the inherent
challenges (real though they are) of responding to tax competition unilaterally.
What
might be a plausible unilateral national welfare objective for a country, like
the 6 that adopted TPR in the survey data? It might be: revenue-maximization
from MNC taxation, adjusted for any negative effect on positive productivity
spillovers.
Two
considerations make the revenue maximization piece especially plausible here.
First, at least for the likes of those 6 countries, the MNCs are likely to be
almost 100 percent owned by foreign shareholders. Thus, taxes on the MNCs that
those shareholders bear economically are likely to transfer wealth from foreign
individuals to the domestic Treasury. Second, the extent to which the MNCs are
earning global rents raises one’s confidence that their shareholders will bear
the MNC taxes economically – a prospect that might be dim indeed if the MNC was
merely earning normal returns that it could also earn elsewhere. So the
presence of rents, and the country’s capacity to reach them, not just the
marginal local returns to real investment, is crucial to this conclusion.
Once
one is actually losing revenue from TPR, things don’t look so great from it.
But this is easy to understand in the framework where we think of TPR as akin
to increasing property-based FA. So the lesson for me is to find other ways of
getting at rents. As my DST-et-al paper discusses (and thus, as will be a
center stage issue at next week’s NYU Tax Policy Colloquium), this inquiry
might lead one in very different directions. It requires that one think further
about such options as (1) sales-based FA and its more sophisticated sibling,
residual profit allocation, and (2) novel tax instruments such as digital
service taxes or diverted profits taxes.
Hi Daniel!
ReplyDeleteThank you for the interesting post! However, the link in the beginning of the post seems to lead to your (very interesting) draft DST article and not to the TRP study in question.