Yesterday
at NYU Law School, I participated in a “debate” with audience voting on
alternative propositions at the annual NYU-KPMG Tax Lecture. Other panelists were Bob Stack from Treasury,
Michael Plowgian, David Rosenbloom, and Paul Oosterhuis, plus Willard Taylor
was the moderator. The debate
propositions were preceded by a talk by Oosterhuis and Rosenbloom on the
Treasury’s newly issued proposed regulations under section 385, which provide
that, in certain cases when one member of an affiliated group distributes what’s
ostensibly a debt instrument to another member of the group, the instrument is
classified as equity, rather than as debt.
The point is to disallow interest deductions by U.S. companies (owned by
foreign companies) that might otherwise serve to strip profits out of the U.S.
tax base – not limited to companies that have recently inverted.
One
point that emerged from the talk was that, in principle, it might have been
better for the Treasury simply to deny interest deductions in these cases,
rather than reclassifying the instruments as equity (which potentially has
broader implications, not necessarily within the purpose being served). But the fact that the Treasury was acting
under section 385, which deals with debt versus equity classification rather
than with the allowance of interest deductions, presumably made this necessary.
Anywhere,
here are the debate propositions, followed by approximations of what I tried to
say.
1) Regulations
proposed 2 weeks ago under section 385 would treat the distribution of a note
to a related foreign person (and similar transactions) as equity, disallowing
any deduction for interest. Is this a
good idea?
Since
the moment the new regulations came out, I have been expecting the net balance
of public commentary to be heavily slanted against them. And while I found the Oosterhuis and
Rosenbloom comments at the session to be thoughtful and fair, I am still
expecting this.
Both
Steve Shay of Harvard Law School and Steve Rosenthal of the Urban-Brookings Tax
Policy Center have been speaking publicly in favor of the regulations. (Shay helped point the Treasury in this
direction.) But most of the other people
who will be commenting have client interests, and/or are comfortable with the
way things were before the regs were issued.
One
possibly countervailing factor, however, is that those who are speaking for or
on behalf of U.S. firms that aren’t inverting may be glad to see foreign firms’
relative advantage in profit-shifting out of the U.S. narrowed by the new rule –
although only “new” earnings-stripping by such firms, as distinct from that
which they already had in place, is potentially impeded.
Academic
types, such as myself, even when willing or strongly inclined to take a
pro-government position, don’t generally go as deep in the weeds as one would
need to go in order to address the rules in detail. (And while we can certainly do legal analysis
of them, we may not be as well-equipped as people in practice to figure out how
the practicalities will develop.) Maybe this
aversion to going deep in the weeds is our bad – but certainly it can affect
the overall tenor of the debate.
That
said, here are four particular observations regarding the new section 385
regulations:
First, section 385
gives the Treasury VERY broad discretion.
So anyone who wants to argue that the regs are invalid is swimming steeply
uphill. It’s true that the regs address
particular practices that were not specifically in Congress’s collective mind
when it enacted the provision in 1969.
But the grant of broad discretion seems clearly to have been meant to
let the Treasury respond to new developments.
Note also that this is not
just an anti-inversion provision.
Second, one could see
the regulation as a small and admittedly discrete move away from separate
entity tax accounting for multinational groups.
Given the general economic significance (and potentially large tax
significance) of the lines between legally distinct but economically integrated
affiliated entities, this is a good direction to be going in.
Third, it’s important,
and probably a good thing, that the regulation addresses “inbound” investment –
i.e., U.S. economic activity by multinationals with a foreign parent – rather
than just inversions. A key reason for
the inversion wave is that, in addressing profit-shifting out of the domestic
tax base, the U.S. rules appear to over-rely on residence-based rules that
apply only to U.S. multinationals, relative to rules that affect foreign
multinationals. This is a topic I’ll be
addressing further in other settings.
Fourth, by acting
unilaterally (here as previously) in response to the recent inversion wave, the
Treasury has rejected old, 1980s-vintage notions of comity between the
branches, by acting on a live and prominent policy topic rather than working
with Congress via the design and enactment of new legislation. But guess what – it isn’t the 1980s
anymore! We now live in a world where
the tax legislative process has generally broken down, unless one party holds
all the levers. This is going to keep
happening in the future, under both Democratic and Republican
administrations. Whether one regrets the
lost 1980s of bipartisan legislation or not, that world is gone, and comity
norms are going to change in consequence.
So one might as well get used to it.
2) Should the EC
retroactively revoke rulings issued by the tax authorities of EU member
states? Are there better ways to address
the concerns? Is revocation consistent
with US tax treaties?
It’s
useful to look at this from an EU standpoint, just so one can understand what
they’re about Then there’s plenty of
time to think about it from a US standpoint.
From
an EU standpoint, it’s totally understandable that they would issue the “state
aid” rulings requiring countries to take back favorable tax rulings that mainly
had been issued to U.S. companies. If
the EC wants to restrain certain types of race-to-the-bottom internal
competition between member states, it can’t let labels (such as the use of the
tax system to deliver what are effectively subsidies) to lead to frustration of
their policy!
Also,
when one is adjudicating the merits of what has been done – in effect
judicially, although the EC is a commission, not a court – of course it will
apply “retroactively.” Saying “Next time
we’ll be really mad!,” and acting only nominally prospectively, would have been
widely scoffed at, and would likely have failed to deliver a credible message
to EU governments.
That
said, from a US standpoint I am concerned about the degree of focus on US
firms. And I also understand that the EU
structure makes it trickier for us to figure out how to negotiate individually
with EU countries. But that’s relevant
to how we should respond – not to whether what they’re doing makes sense from
their standpoint.
One
last point, however – while the US doesn’t benefit directly – indeed, it loses –
when a given US company (with mainly US shareholders) ends up paying more tax
to EU countries, we may benefit indirectly in the long run, if it lowers the
expected after-tax return to US companies from profit-shifting out of the US.
To
put it differently, the EU may have affected its prospective tax-attractiveness,
and this potentially benefits the US insofar as there is zero-sum tax
competition at work between us.
3) Given the
EC’s almost exclusive focus on US companies, should the US invoke section 891?
This provision permits us to double the
tax rates on residents of foreign companies that subject US taxpayers to
discriminatory taxes. The apparent EU
focus on US companies in the state aid cases has led some to urge that we
consider invoking this provision. (BTW,
the chance that this will actually happen is probably about zero.)
I think of it this way. In principle, bluffing is great, if one
specifies in advance that it will actually work. So if we threatened to invoke §891 and won
valuable concessions of some kind from the Europeans, great.
But it’s hard to bluff effectively if
you aren’t actually willing to pull the trigger. And here I don’t think we should, plus the
Europeans surely know that we won’t, plus there is also a downside to attempted
Trumpist bullying.
So no, on balance we shouldn’t invoke
section 891 or even waste too much breath pretending to think about it.
How should we respond, insofar as we’re
seriously concerned about the focus on US companies? I’d say, by doing something we might actually
want to do anyway – doing more to address profit-shifting out of the US by EU
(and other non-US) companies.
4) Is the US
discussion of international tax reform disproportionately focused on “outward”
investment by US corporations? What about foreign investment in the US? Can the two be separated?
Is this in part
what the §385 regulations are about? Should the US consider a US version of the
UK “diverted profits” Tax? Should the US challenge supply chain structures
and/or significantly broaden and tighten the earnings-stripping rules?
The
inbound and outbound rules are closely conceptually linked. These days, our main reason for taxing
outbound is to address profit-shifting out of the US by US companies. Likewise, our inbound rules address
profit-shifting out of the US by non-US companies.
So
it’s the same problem, just involving different groups of companies. And of the two sets of rules get too out of
whack, you get incentives for inversions, among other things.
The
US rules may be too lax overall on profit-shifting out of the US – although
that is legitimately debatable.
But
what’s clear is that we’re more lax in this regard on inbound than
outbound. So even if we can do a better
job addressing outbound by US companies, we need to bring those rules into
balance with those for inbound investment.
Transfer
pricing and earnings- stripping are the 2 obvious places to focus.
Finally,
without endorsing the particulars of the UK diverted profits tax, it’s
definitely an example of seeking to address domestic tax avoidance by
non-resident companies.
5) Without any
way to force members to sign on, is BEPS going anywhere? Will it become
irrelevant? Will it make a meaningful contribution to the international tax
rules or just cause disruption?
I’d
restate the question as: Is the glass ¼ full or ¾ empty?
I
expect BEPS’s true results to fall far short of the rhetoric and expectations. I wish had a dollar for every speaker at
every conference on OECD-BEPS over the last 3 years. I’d be a rich man.
From
all that attention, you might think it would end up being a bigger deal than it
actually is going to be.
But
you can’t force members to sign on – views and interests differ – and the BEPS
methodology, such as continuing to rely on separate-company accounting within
affiliated groups, is a bit unpromising for BEPS.
That
said, some real changes may indeed not just emerge but persist. But the main thing is that, if the global tax
policy climate has indeed changed, BEPS may be remembered as a harbinger or
leading edge of this change, even if what really matters is that change, rather
than its particular content.
6) If the US
corporate tax rate on US multinational income is reduced, should pass-through
entities help pay for the reduction?
Lowering
the corporate rate ought to be fully financed.
Otherwise, we worsen the long-term budget picture and hand windfall
gains to current investors, who are generally from the top of the income and
wealth distribution.
Base-broadening
(from an income tax standpoint) that applies to the pass-through sector as well
as the corporate sector is the logical way to do it. This obviously implies raising taxes for
pass-throughs.
Is
that so bad? Well, I think it verges on
making corporate tax reform a political non-starter. But it might not be so bad
in substance for one very simple reason.
Recent research suggests that the partnership sector (although not sub S
corps or proprietorships) is currently comparatively lightly taxed. So the shift in taxes from the corporate to
the pass-through sector might tend towards equalizing their overall tax
burdens.
Two
final points about broadening the base to pay for corporate rate cuts. First, even if it’s revenue-neutral, it tends
to hand a windfall to existing investment, at the expense of new investment. That generally isn’t a great idea.
No comments:
Post a Comment